Ricardo Hausmann
Ricardo Hausmann, a former minister
of planning of Venezuela and former Chief Economist of the
Inter-American Development Bank, is Professor of the Practice of
Economic Development at Harvard University, where he is also Director of
the Center for International Development. He is Chair of the World
Eco… read more
Redistribution or Inclusion?
RIYADH – The issue of rising income inequality loomed large at this year’s World Economic Forum in Davos.
As is well known, the United States’ economy has grown significantly
over the past three decades, but the median family’s income has not. The
top 1% (indeed, the top .01%) have captured most of the gains,
something that societies are unlikely to tolerate for long.
Many fear that this is a global phenomenon with similar causes everywhere, a key claim in Thomas Piketty’s celebrated book Capital in Twenty-First Century. But this proposition may be dangerously misleading.
It is crucial to distinguish inequality in productivity among firms from unequal distribution of income within
firms. The traditional battle between labor and capital has been about
the latter, with workers and owners fighting over their share of the
pie. But there is surprisingly deep inequality in firms’ productivity,
which means that the size of the pie varies radically. This is
especially true in developing countries, where it is common to find
differences in productivity of a factor of ten at the provincial or
state level and many times higher at the municipal level.
These
two very different sources of inequality are often conflated, which
prevents clear thinking on either one. Both are related to a similar
feature of modern production: the fact that it requires many
complementary inputs. This includes not only raw materials and machines,
which can be shipped around, but also many specialized labor skills,
infrastructure, and rules, which cannot be moved easily and hence need
to be spatially collocated. A shortage of any of these inputs can have
disastrous effects on productivity.
This
complementarity makes many parts of the developing world unsuitable for
modern production, because key inputs are missing. Even within cities,
poor areas are so disconnected and inadequately endowed that
productivity is dismal. As a result, there are huge disparities among
firms in terms of efficiency – and hence in the income they can
distribute.
Given
productivity constraints, redistribution is only palliative, not
curative. To address the problem requires investing in inclusion,
endowing people with skills, and connecting them to the inputs and
networks that can make them productive.
The
dilemma is that poor countries lack the means to connect all places to
all inputs. They are faced with the choice of connecting a few places to
most inputs and getting high productivity there, or putting some of the
inputs in all places and getting very little productivity growth
everywhere. That is why development tends to be unequal.
The other
problem of modern production is how to distribute the income generated
by all of the complementary inputs. Today, production is carried out not
just by individuals, or even by teams of people within firms, but also
by teams of firms, or value chains. Just look at the credits at the end
of any contemporary film. Complementarity thus creates a problem of
attribution. How should credit for the final product be allocated, and
to whom?
Economists
have traditionally believed that each team member is paid her
opportunity cost, that is, the highest income she could receive if she
were kicked off the team. In this context, if markets are characterized
by what economists call perfect competition, once the opportunity cost
of all inputs has been paid, there is nothing left to distribute. But in
real life, the team is worth more – often much more – than the
opportunity cost of its members.
Who
gets to pocket this “team surplus”? Traditionally, the assumption has
been that it accrues to shareholders. But the rise of extreme CEO
compensation in the US, documented by Piketty and others, may reflect
CEOs’ ability to disrupt the team if they do not get part of the
surplus. After all, CEOs experience precipitous income declines when
they are kicked out, indicating that they were paid far more than their
opportunity cost.
In
the case of successful start-ups, the money paid when they are acquired
or go public accrues to those who put the team together. For more
conventional value chains, the surplus tends to go to the inputs that
have greater market power. Business schools teach their students to
capture the maximum surplus in the value chain by focusing on inputs
that are difficult for others to provide while ensuring that other
inputs are “commoditized” and hence cannot capture more than their
opportunity cost.
The
gains do not accrue to the most deserving. The rise of “capital,” which
Piketty documents in France and other countries, is caused mostly by
the appreciation of real estate, simply because good locations become
more valuable in an increasingly networked economy. As with land, the
current intellectual property-rights regime, by over-protecting old ideas, may provide market power that not only exacerbates income inequality but also hurts innovation.
This
means that policies aimed at ensuring an equitable outcome should rely
on either owning or taxing the inputs that capture the “team surplus.”
One reason why Singapore has a well-funded government, despite low
taxes, is that its successful policies caused the land and real estate
it owned to explode in value, generating a huge revenue stream.
Similarly,
the Colombian city of MedellĂn funds itself from the profits of its
successful utility company, which is now a multinational player. The
economist Dani Rodrik recently suggested that
governments should fund themselves from the dividends earned by
investing in public venture funds, thus socializing the gains from
innovation.
Of
course, capturing this surplus may allow for income redistribution, as
many suggest; but a much bigger and sustainable bang can be achieved if
the proceeds go instead to financing inclusion. In the end, inclusive
growth may generate a more prosperous and egalitarian society, whereas
redistribution may fail to benefit either inclusion or growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment