Michael Spence
Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in
economics, is Professor of Economics at NYU’s Stern School of Business,
Distinguished Visiting Fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations,
Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University, Academic
Board Chairman of the Asia Global Institute in Hong … read more
FORT
LAUDERDALE, FLORIDA – Developing countries are facing major obstacles –
many of which they have little to no control over – to achieving
sustained high growth. Beyond the headwinds generated by slow
advanced-economy growth and abnormal post-crisis monetary and financial
conditions, there are the disruptive impacts of digital technology,
which are set to erode developing economies’ comparative advantage in
labor-intensive manufacturing activities. With the reversal of these
trends out of the question, adaptation is the only option.
Robotics has already
made significant inroads in electronics assembly, with sewing trades,
traditionally many countries’ first entry point to the global trading
system, likely to come next. As this trend continues, the imperative to
build supply chains based on the location of relatively immobile and
cost-effective labor will wane, with production moving closer to the
final market. Adidas, for example, is already building a factory in
Germany, where robots will produce high-end athletic shoes, and is
planning a second one in the United States.
Given all of this,
developing countries need to act now to adapt their growth strategies. A
sensible framework for doing so must account for several key factors.
First, the problems
in advanced countries – from slow economic growth to political
uncertainty – are likely to persist, reducing potential growth
everywhere for an extended period. In this context, developing countries
must not succumb to the temptation to try to boost demand through
unsustainable means, such as the accumulation of excess debt.
Instead, developing
countries, particularly those in the earlier stages of economic
development, must find new external markets for their goods, by
maximizing trade opportunities with their counterparts in the developing
world, many of which have considerable purchasing power. While such
demand will surely not offset the drop in advanced-country demand
completely, it can help to soften the blow.
Second, investment,
both public and private, remains a powerful growth engine. In economies
with excess productive capacity, targeted investment can yield a double
benefit, generating short-run demand and boosting growth and
productivity thereafter. Given this, shortfalls in investment that
promises high social and private returns must be reduced, and even
eliminated.
These growth- and
productivity-enhancing investments should be financed primarily from
domestic savings, though some can also be financed with debt. Long-term,
stable infrastructure investments can be financed at least partly by
international development institutions.
Third, it is critical
to manage the capital account in a way that protects and enhances the
real economy’s growth potential. Large inflows of capital from countries
with low interest rates can easily push up exchange rates, putting the
tradable part of the economy under pressure. At the same time, the
prospect of a capital-flow reversal adds risk, deters investment, and
can produce sudden credit-tightening events.
In this context,
selective capital controls and careful reserve management can help to
stabilize the balance of payments and ensure that the terms of trade do
not change too fast to be offset by productivity growth. In fact,
successful developing countries were pursuing such policies even before
the global economic crisis hit.
Fourth, a realistic
approach to the digital revolution is needed. On one hand, developing
countries should recognize that disruption, while happening fast, will
not render their growth models obsolete overnight. China’s continued
growth and rising household income are creating opportunities for
lower-income economies in low-cost manufacturing.
On the other hand,
developing countries must accept the inevitability of changes to their
growth models caused by digital technologies. Instead of viewing these
changes as a threat, and trying to resist them, developing economies
should be getting ahead of them, by embracing disruptive innovations.
This means investing in the capacity – physical and human – to support
their use.
Beyond upgrading
manufacturing, developing countries should be preparing for the shift
toward services that they will inevitably undergo as incomes rise
(though the precise timing is hard to predict). Indeed, they should be
seeking ways to exploit opportunities to boost their trade in services,
much like India and the Philippines have done.
Fifth, the
distribution of gains from economic growth cannot be ignored. The
advanced economies tried that, and the result has been rising political
polarization, intensifying anti-establishment sentiment, declining
policy coherence, and weakening social cohesion. In a low-growth
environment, in particular, developing countries cannot afford to make
the same mistake.
Sixth, it is
important to establish sustainable growth patterns early on. A “green”
approach would not only stimulate additional growth; it would also be
likely to increase the quality of growth, not to mention the lives of
ordinary people. Moreover, it will lead to a far more resilient economy
in the long run.
Finally,
entrepreneurial activity is vital to translate economic potential into
reality. Policies that support such activity, such as by removing
obstacles to new business creation and enhancing financing
opportunities, cannot be left out of growth strategies. Opening channels
for flows of information, ideas, expertise, and talent from abroad can
only enhance these efforts.
Developing economies
may not have much control over the headwinds that they face today, but
that does not mean that they are powerless. Much can be done not just to
sustain moderate growth, but also to secure a more prosperous and
resilient future.
No comments:
Post a Comment