Stephen Moore: Why a Balanced Budget Amendment is Necessary
. . .
Thank you for the opportunity to testify on behalf of the Balanced Budget Amendment.
I
have been working on federal budget issues in Washington for more than
30 years and when I first started, the budget was just less than $1
trillion and the deficit was just over $100 billion. At the time, a $100
billion budget deficit was seen as financially ruinous and a symptom of
our political disregard for future generations. I worked for Ronald
Reagan when we embarrassingly proposed the first $1 trillion budget in
1986.
I
shudder when I think about what has happened in the succeeding 30
years. First, the budget is not $1 trillion, but it is now $4 trillion
and inflation only accounts for about half of this increase. Deficits of
the unthinkable level of $100 billion have now reached as high as $1.5
trillion and are headed back in that direction. And the national debt of
$3 trillion is now $19 trillion.
We
are tempting fate here. It seems as though we are in a contest to see
how fiscally reckless we can be in Washington before the whole system
collapses. It is like the game of Jenga that I play with my kids, where
we keep putting blocks on top of the tower and hope that it doesn’t
topple on our watch. But it eventually crashes.
I
was at first not a big fan of a balanced budget amendment and I have to
confess that I believed the critics who said, we just need to show some
backbone and courage; we don’t need to mess with the Constitution. But
neither party has shown the courage or backbone to do anything about
federal spending and borrowing. They won’t – and the institution is
inherently incapable of doing so. To ask Congress to restrain its
spending is like asking a cat to put a bell on itself. So $17 trillion
of debt later, I now believe a new fiscal constitution is necessary for
America. And it will only happen when the people rise up and demand it.
The first step is for Congress to pass the BBA and send it to the states
and people where we can then have a great and long overdue national
debate about our fiscal future.
A
balanced budget amendment should set new rules that outlaw federal
borrowing except in extraordinary circumstances. It should take a
supermajority to authorize new borrowing. It should also take a
supermajority vote to raise taxes.
False Criticisms of the Balanced Budget Amendment
I would like to address a few of the false concerns about the Balanced Budget Amendment.
The
first is the idea that deficits are good for the economy when times are
tough. This was the Keynesian notion that it is appropriate and even
proper to borrow during times of economic stagnation and that there is a
“multiplier effect” to government spending and borrowing.
This
is clearly false in theory and in practice. Government spending and
borrowing doesn’t stimulate growth, because it crowds out private sector
spending and resources. When the government borrows, it must issue
bonds and someone must purchase the bonds. Every dollar the government
receives from bondholders to spend is exactly offset by a dollar the
bondholders withdraw from the economy in buying the bonds. This is money
that could have been spent or money that could have been loaned to a
private business, but is now diverted to the government. So the net
effect of government borrowing and spending on the economy even in the
short term is at best zero, and probably negative because government
gets a lower return on its spending than private actors.
History
confirms this. After eight years of the first grand Keynesian
experiment -- the New Deal during the Great Depression -- the
unemployment rate in 1939 was 20.7 percent and output was still growing
at a crawl, seven years after Franklin Delano Roosevelt took office.
That's some victory. As Burton Fulsom, author of the Depression history
New Deal or Raw Deal, has argued: "The greatest myth of the twentieth
century is that Franklin Roosevelt's New Deal ended the Great
Depression." Folsom, Burton W. New Deal or Raw Deal?: How FDR's Economic
Legacy Has Damaged America. New York, NY: Threshold Editions, 2008.
Xiii.
Japan
has employed textbook Keynesianism for 20 years and nearly the whole
island has been paved over by public works projects financed by record
levels of debt, yet the economy continues to flounder and asset values
are still only half what they were in 1990.
The
most thorough recent repudiation of Keynes has been the Great Recession
of 2008– 2011. Never in modern times has the premise that
open-checkbook government spending and pedal- to-the-metal money
creation lead to economic growth been put to such a large-scale trial.
The government borrowed $7 trillion in six years and produced the
flimsiest recovery among all recessions post-World War II.
The
Obama economics team predicted a “multiplier effect” from all of the
Obama debt spending. Obama’s Agriculture Secretary Tom Vilsack forecast
that food stamps would be an "economic stimulus" and that "every dollar
of benefits generates $1.84 in the economy in terms of economic
activity." “Obama Ag Secretary Vilsack: Food Stamps Are A ‘Stimulus’”, Real Clear Politics, August 16, 2011 (Accessed January 6, 2016). They
saw no negative effects from giving people money and food in exchange
for not working. If Vilsack had been right then we should have put every
American on food stamps.
Here
are the facts. When President Obama came into office, the recession,
which started in December, 2007, was already 12 months old. There have
been 11 other recessions since the Great Depression. The average
duration of those recessions was 10 months. So the recovery was already
overdue when he came into office. All he really had to do was stay out
of the way. But he didn’t stay out of the way. He took the country on an
unprecedented, throwback, Keynesian economics bender, which only
delayed rather than promoted recovery, just as it did in the 1930s.
The Obama stimulus bill was almost a complete failure in creating jobs even using Barack Obama’s own economic analysis.
Mr.
Obama’s White House economics team famously predicted in 2009 that
every dollar of additional federal borrowing would lead to about $1.50
cents of additional economic activity due to the supposed “multiplier
effect” of government spending on private activity. Mark
Zandi, “The Economic Outlook and Stimulus Options,” Moody’s
Economy.com, Testimony before the U.S. Senate Budget Committee, November
19, 2008, Table 1, p. 10 (accessed January 8, 2016) (Zandi
asserts that for each dollar of new government spending: temporary food
stamps adds $1.73 to the economy, extended unemployment benefits adds
$1.63, increased infrastructure spending adds $1.59, and aid to state
and local governments adds$1.38. Jointly, these figures imply that, in a
recession, a typical dollar in new deficit spending expands the economy
by roughly $1.50).
The
White House economics team also analyzed what would happen to
unemployment during the first several years of the coming recovery with
and without the $800 billion stimulus bill. Not only did unemployment
turn out to be higher than was projected with the extra spending, but
the unemployment rate was also consistently higher with the stimulus
spending than the White House had projected would be the case if
Congress had not borrowed and spent all this money. So we would have
been better off doing nothing. Apologists like Paul Krugman of the New
York Times argue that the stimulus “wasn’t big enough.” Paul Krugman, “How Did We Know The Stimulus Was Too Small,” The New York Times, July 28, 2010 (accessed January 7, 2016). But
over the last six years the U.S. government has increased the debt by
more than $7 trillion. It seems highly implausible that more debt would
have led to more growth.
In
sum, we have had higher unemployment with the stimulus than we would
have had without the stimulus – by Obama’s own admission. What is worse
is that the money has all been spent. Now the U.S. is only left with
debt repayments and very slow growth.
The
second myth is that our deficit is under control now. No it isn’t. Our
debt burden is expected to escalate over the next two decades at least
as baby boomers continue to move into partial and then full retirement. Congressional
Budget Office, “The 2015 Long-Term Budget Outlook,” Table 6-1: Long-Run
Effects on the Federal Budget of the Fiscal Policies in Various Budget
Scenarios, June 16, 2015 (Accessed January 4, 2016). Boomers
will eventually collect hundreds of billions and then over time
trillions of dollars of benefits through the government’s biggest three
income transfer programs: Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. The
money will come from their children and grandchildren one way or the
other.
The
Congressional Budget Office sees publicly-held debt rising to 107
percent of GDP by the year 2040.5 If things don’t go as planned, an
alternative scenario has the debt rising to 175% of GDP over the same
time period. Almost every independent economist and financial analyst
agrees that debt levels this high are dangerous and debilitating to
America’s economic superpower status.
In
short, a grim fiscal future may soon confront us. But it is not
inevitable. The course can be changed before the average family of four
owes close to $500,000 in federal debt.
The
third myth of our debt is that we can’t grow our way out of this
problem. Maybe not entirely, but without growth we will never cut
spending enough and raise enough revenue to get anywhere near balance.
One
very big reason the burden of the debt has exploded so suddenly has
been the slow growth of the economy over the past decade or so. The
relationship between economic growth and the debt is often
under-appreciated. Each extra percentage point of growth over a decade
generates at least $2 trillion of additional revenues over a decade. But
one percentage point lower growth operates in the opposite fashion with
roughly $2 trillion in lower revenues after a decade. The negative
feedback loop of debt is self-reinforcing. A slow economy leads to more
debt, which leads to a slower economy, and the cycle keeps getting
worse.
We’ve
been diverted away from high growth in the last decade and a half.
Here’s a way of quantifying the problem. The U.S. economy sustained a
real rate of economic growth of 3.3% from 1945 to 1973, and achieved
closer to 3.4% sustained real growth from 1982 to 2007. Over the past
decade growth has slowed to an anemic 1.5%.6
At
a real rate of economic growth of 3.3%, national output and income
would double every 21 years. After another 21 years it would double
again, achieving nearly four times the original level. After another 21
years, it would double yet again, achieving nearly eight times
the original national output and income. So by 2060 we would have at
least $60 trillion more GDP and that would substantially reduce the
burden of the debt.
What Are the Risks from Our National Debt?
I see four immediate dangers to our high and rising levels of debt:
America
is vulnerable to an interest rate move that could make financing the
debt and deficit spending massively expensive.Government borrowing in an
advanced nation with sophisticated financial markets like the United
States doesn’t seem to impact interest rates much.
But what happens if for other reasons interest rates rise? What is the government’s exposure to an interest rate spike?
For
the past five years or so, interest rates on 10 year Treasury bills
have hovered around 2% with a slight upward movement in the last couple
of years.
But
what happens if this low-interest rate party comes to an end? We have
already seen over the last 18 months a gradual rise in interest rates.
If that trend continues or accelerates, the economic and financial
repercussions could be severe.
CBO
performed a sensitivity analysis of the federal government’s
expenditures for interest payments based on a higher interest rate
scenario in the future.
CBO’s
baseline model projects that publicly-held debt will rise to 107
percent of GDP by 2040. According to the sensitivity analysis, if
interest rates each year are on average 0.75 percentage points higher
(hardly an unrealistic assumption) than in the baseline, then the public
debt in 2040 will climb even higher, to 130 percent of GDP.
The
average rate on ten year treasuries is a little over 6 percent. This is
2.75 percentage points higher than today. If rates migrate to their
historical average, then interest rate charges over 10 years will rise
by roughly $4.0 trillion. This means the cost for interest on the debt
will nearly double from $400 billion a year to $800 billion a year.
Interest rate payments will then rival or even exceed national defense
spending, Social Security, and Medicare as the most expensive item in
the budget.
By
the way, Congress labors mightily to come up with deficit reduction
plans to come up with plans that will erase $3 trillion from the debt
over 10 years. If interest rates rise to just their traditional levels,
the harmful impact of those higher rates would erase every penny of the
progress from the most ambitious of all imaginable deficit reduction
plans. .
Next
we have to consider a “worse case scenario” with rates rising to 7%.
Although we think the likelihood of this scenario playing out is small,
it is worth considering the down side risk. Under that scenario,
interest payments alone rise to above $1 trillion a year. This would
make interest payments by far the single largest expenditure item in the
budget. It would mean that well over half of all income taxes paid
would be used to pay for interest on the debt. More and more taxes would
be paid not for current services like roads, bridges, health care,
national security, the courts, law enforcement, etc., but to pay for
past spending. This could send the federal government into a debt death
spiral of ever- rising taxes to pay for ever rising levels of debt.
The
national debt could necessitate the largest tax increase in American
history – which would severely damage the U.S. economy.
A
second major economic threat from the debt is the potential tax
increases that might be necessary in the future to pay down the debt.
Bills have to be paid at some point. No one and no government can borrow
forever at ever rising levels. Economic growth will reduce the carrying
cost of the debt, but it won’t erase it.
So
the issue becomes: what happens if Congress tries to finance deficit
reduction by raising taxes? How much are taxpayers going to be on the
hook to pay for past and continuing borrowing? We have to add here the
cost of unfunded liabilities as well. While these are not legal
obligations to pay, as are government bonds, it seems unlikely that
Congress is likely to renege on past promises to pay Social Security and
Medicare benefits as more than 70 million baby boomers continue to
retire. The borrowing costs will certainly rise and as deficits and
interest payments rise, as is expected by the Congressional Budget
Office. CBO projects higher not lower deficits in the years to come.
The
pressure to raise taxes could be insurmountable politically. This
pressure will come from lobbying groups that want to retain high levels
of spending on social security, medicare, education, and national
defense programs. If spending isn’t cut, how high could taxes have to
rise to cover the costs of paying for current programs?
Several
years ago the Congressional Budget Office provided these calculations.
CBO found that if spending isn’t cut, tax rates on corporations would
have to rise to 88% on corporations, near 90% on individuals, and the
middle class tax rate would more than double to more than 60%. The
following chart shows the numbers versus current tax rates.
The
impact of tax rates this high would be economically catastrophic. On
the corporate side, the U.S. already has the highest rate in the world
at 35%. An 88% corporate tax rate would induce nearly every Fortune 100
company in America to leave for foreign shores. This would be a
devastating turn of events for workers as millions of jobs were
outsourced to foreign countries with much lower tax rates.
On
the individual side, tax rates of near 90% would cause less work, less
investment, and less business formation. Most businesses pay their taxes
through the individual tax code, so an 80 or 90% tax rate would slow
business creation and expansion to a crawl. The last time rates were
this high was in the 1970s when the economy stalled out in a series of
crippling recessions. The average individual tax rate around the world
is between 30 and 40%, under this CBO scenario, the U.S. tax rate would
be double the average. American competitiveness in global markets would
be crippled.
Higher
tax rates are a deterrent to growth. We know, for example, that low tax
rate states, have much faster job growth and economic output than high
tax states. Texas with no income tax, had more job creation from 2007-13
than all other states combined. A study by ALEC found that since 1970,
the no-income tax states had twice the pace of job creation as the high
income tax states. The U.S. economy boomed in the 1920s, 1960s and 1980s
when tax rates were lowered. High tax eras like the 1930s, the 1970s
and the Obama years are associated with recession and/or slow growth. We
estimate that income tax rates of more than 50% would have a very
negative effect on capital investment in the United States and the worry
is the sizable and growing federal debt makes this scenario more
plausible in the years to come. This is one giant risk premium from the
debt.
CBO,
makes this point about the risks of rising tax rates: “Increases in
marginal tax rates on labor and capital income reduce output and income
below what they would be with lower rates (all else held equal).” That
recognition deserves to be applauded, though we think CBO doesn’t even
accurately account for the full contractionary effect that such higher
marginal tax rates would produce.
Current high levels of debt make America vulnerable to a financial crisis if another recession hits.
Usually,
as recoveries from recession roll on, we squirrel away extra revenues
in a rainy day fund – states do this, for example – to have money in
reserve to prepare for the next recession. Uncle Sam doesn’t have a
rainy day fund. In fact, seven years into a recovery, the government is
still running half trillion dollar deficits, with the forecast that
these deficits will migrate back up to $1 trillion on the current
course.
The
U.S. is in no financial shape to weather a new recession. If the
economy dips into negative territory in the next few years, which would
be predictable, based on historical boom and bust cycles, neither family
nor federal finances are in any condition to weather the storm. Federal
revenues would crash and spending would spike. Something has to give.
Here
is the danger, with a normal recession hitting, we could easily see
debt levels rise to 300% of GDP and that has historically been a hole
too deep for a nation to dig out
of.
This could trigger the kind of debt death spiral that would cause a
severe loss of living standards in the U.S. It is the Greece scenario.
The prudent course of action is to cut spending and debt now, so as to
be better prepared financially for the next market crash.
Federal deficit spending is already “crowding out” private sector borrowing and capital investment.
As
discussed above, we don’t see much evidence that the debt and deficits
of the federal government are raising interest rates. But we do observe a
related unhealthy “squeezing out” phenomenon from the deluge of
government borrowing. With our colleague David Malpass, we have
discovered a disturbing pattern in which massive government borrowing
has corresponded with a flattening out and even declining level of
borrowing in the private sector. Tight credit is a major problem in the
economy. That is driven by new financial regulations for sure. But it is
also being driven in part by government’s pushing out private
borrowing.
Since
2007 two of every three dollars of credit in the U.S. economy has been
diverted to government, and only one of three finances private sector
activity. When private investment dries up, so do living standards and
wages.
Conclusion: Living on Borrowed Time and Dollars
The
2014 Congressional Concurrent Resolution on the Budget states,
“Interest payments on the debt (the ‘legacy cost’ of deficit spending)
will sum to a staggering $5.6 trillion over the next decade according to
the Congressional Budget Office.” This is the case even though CBO
assumes the real rate of interest on federal debt remains below 1
percent throughout the entire 10 year period. As previously stated, if
the rate rises, the borrowing costs and deficits will accelerate and the
ten year forecast looks daunting.
They
also look dangerous and debilitating. For much of the post war period
the ratio of U.S. government debt to the size of the economy averaged
about 36 percent. Under President Obama, the debt ratio has shot up to
exceed 75 percent in 2013. Even that isn’t what is so worrisome.
It
is that the debt is not expected to fall back down again but to remain
at this new high-level plateau and if anything continue to climb. Only a
balanced budget amendment to the Constitution will reverse this
frightening fiscal future.
No comments:
Post a Comment